Sunday, March 5, 2017

Study Sheds Light on Cost-Competitive Alternatives to ‘Buy And Dry’ - EDF urges Colorado policy makers to think differently about water management

A new economic study released January 11, 2017 by Environmental Defense Fund and WestWater Research shows that Alternative Transfer Methods (ATMs) are cost competitive with traditional water acquisition methods, challenging the conventional wisdom in Colorado that it’s too expensive and risky for municipalities to lease water.

ATMs are techniques for temporarily allocating and distributing agricultural water between different users, providing more flexibility to both agriculture producers and municipalities and reducing the need to permanently transfer water rights, which can result in “buy and dry”.

To satisfy the water supply needs of Colorado’s growing population, municipalities have been buying up agricultural land for its water rights. This practice of “buy and dry” is projected to take 500,000-700,000 acres of agricultural land out of production by 2050, or roughly 20% of irrigated farmland in the state.

“We’ve known for a long time that ATMs are better for farms and ranches, better for rural communities and better for the environment,” said Brian Jackson, EDF Associate Director. “And now we can add ‘cost effective’ to the list of benefits.”
Horsetooth Reservoir, part of the Colorado-Big Thompson Project, is located in Larimer County in northern Colorado.
Colorado’s Water Plan, approved in 2015, promotes the use of more ATMs, setting a policy goal of 50,000 acre-feet of ATM projects in place by 2030. Progress towards this goal has lagged due to a number of technical, legal and financial challenges.

But according to the EDF/WestWater study, new policies and state initiatives have begun to ease these challenges, opening the door for ATMs to be used more broadly. “We wanted to see if these changes had the potential to make ATMs easier and less costly to implement,” said Brett Bovee, WestWater Intermountain Regional Director.

The answer is yes. And with wider adoption of ATMs and other water conservation measures, the need for “buy and dry” and water storage projects will be diminished. “This presents a new opportunity for cities to help sustain agriculture, minimize costs and incorporate environmental benefits while planning to meet water supply needs.” said Bovee.

The report identified example ATMs in Colorado and other Western states, and selected two municipalities – the Town of Windsor and the City of Fountain in Colorado – to serve as case-studies. Using a 30-year financial model and accounting for recent changes in Colorado’s water right laws, the report found that ATM approaches had similar, and in some cases, less expensive costs when compared with permanent water right acquisitions.

For example, in the Town of Windsor, researchers compared an ATM lease agreement with a permanent water right acquisition to address projected shortages over a 30-year period. The ATM lease agreement was found to save an average of $200 per acre-foot per year over the traditional approach.

Wednesday, March 1, 2017

Beach Recreationalists' Willingness to Pay and Economic Implications of Coastal Water Quality Problems in Hawaii

Abstract:
The economic value of water quality is poorly understood in Hawaii. Quantifying the economic value of coastal water quality would inform policy decisions that impact the coast and help justify expenditures in water quality improvements. We conducted a non-market valuation of beach recreationalists’ preferences and willingness to pay for water quality and associated attributes at Oahu beaches. Using a discrete choice experiment analyzed by a conditional logit model, results suggest individuals were willing to pay $11.43 per day at the beach to reduce days of bacterial exceedance from 11 to 5 per year, a further $30.72 to reduce it to no bacterial exceedances at all. WTP to move from 15 ft to 30 ft of underwater visibility was $35.71, a further $14.80 to increase from 30 ft to 60 ft. Respondents were also willing to pay $15.33 to improve coral reef cover from 10% to 25%, a further $4.89 to improve to 45% cover. WTP for moving from 9 fish species to 18 species was $7.14, a further $2.47 to increase that to 27 fish species. These environmental improvements can improve Oahu recreationalists’ welfare by $205 million, $550 million, $639 million, $265 million, $274 million, $88 million, $128 million, and $44 million per year, respectively. Welfare gains may justify increased spending in management and restoration of coastal ecosystems.
File:Sea turtles on beach in hawaii.jpg
by Marcus Peng 1 and Kirsten L.L. Oleson 1 and 2
1. University of Hawaiʻi at Mānoa Department of Natural Resources and Environmental Management, 1910 East-West Road, Honolulu, Hawaii, USA
2. University of Hawaiʻi Economic Research Organization, 2424 Maile Way, Honolulu, HI, USA
Ecological Economics via Elsevier Science Direct www.ScienceDirect.com
Volume 136, June 2017, Pages 41–52, Available online 17 February 2017
Keywords: Non-market valuation; Discrete choice experiment; Water quality; Underwater visibility; Coral reefs; Fish diversity; Beach recreation; Oahu; Hawaii

What are Households Willing to Pay for Improved Water Access? Results from a Meta-Analysis

Abstract:
Although several factors contribute to low rates of access to improved water and sanitation in the developing world, it is especially important to understand and measure household demand for these services. One valuable source of information regarding demand is the growing empirical literature that has applied stated preference methods to estimate households' willingness to pay (WTP). Because it is difficult to generalize and support planning based on this scattered literature, we conduct a meta-analysis to take stock of the worldwide sample of household WTP for improved drinking water services. Using 171 WTP estimates drawn from 60 studies, we first describe this sample and then examine the potential factors that explain variation in WTP estimates. Our results suggest that households are willing to pay between approximately $3 and $30 per month for improvements in water access. Specifically, in line with economic theory and intuition, WTP is sensitive to scope (the magnitude of improvement in drinking water services), as well as household income, and stated-preference elicitation method. We demonstrate how our results can be used to predict household-level WTP for selected improvements in drinking water access in regions with low coverage, and find that private benefits exceed the cost of provision.
The LifeStraw is a genius new invention
http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0921800916308953
by George L. Van Houtven 1, Subhrendu K. Pattanayak 2, Faraz Usmani 3, Jui-Chen Yang 4 formerly 1 
1. RTI International, Research Triangle Park, NC, USA
2. Sanford School of Public Policy, Duke University, Durham, NC, USA
3. Nicholas School of the Environment, Duke University, Durham, NC, USA
4. Pacific Economic Research, LLC, Bellevue, WA, USA
Ecological Economics via Elsevier Science Direct www.ScienceDirect.com
Volume 136; June, 2017; Pages 126–135; Available online 23 February 2017
Keywords: Meta-analysis; Water; Sanitation; Contingent valuation; Willingness to pay

Do Energy Efficiency Investments Deliver at the Right Time?

Abstract:
Electricity cannot be cost-effectively stored even for short periods of time. Consequently, wholesale electricity prices vary widely across hours of the day with peak prices frequently exceeding off-peak prices by a factor of ten or more. Most analyses of energy-efficiency policies ignore this variation, focusing on total energy savings without regard to when those savings occur. In this paper we demonstrate the importance of this distinction using novel evidence from a rebate program for air conditioners in Southern California. We estimate electricity savings using hourly smart-meter data and show that savings tend to occur during hours when the value of electricity is high. This significantly increases the overall value of the program, especially once we account for the large capacity payments received by generators to guarantee their availability in high-demand hours. We then compare this estimated savings profile with engineering-based estimates for this program as well as a variety of alternative energy-efficiency investments. The results illustrate a surprisingly large amount of variation in economic value across investments.
...
Before smart meters and other advanced metering infrastructure, it was impossible to measure policy impacts at the hourly level.... Meters were only read once per billing cycle. This situation is rapidly changing. Today in the United States more than 40% of residential electricity customers have smart meters, up from less than 2% in 2007. ...
Savings are strongly correlated with the value of electricity, making the program 48% more valuable than under a naive calculation ignoring timing. As we demonstrate, including capacity payments is important in this calculation. Most of the value of electricity in ultra-peak hours is captured by forward capacity payments to generators to guarantee their availability
...
Across six major U.S. markets, we find that air conditioning investments are on average 29% more valuable than under a naive calculation ignoring timing. 
For commercial and industrial heat pumps and chillers the "timing premiums" are 29% and 
25%, respectively. Other investments like refrigerators and freezers have timing premiums 
below 5% because savings are only weakly correlated with value. Lighting also does surprisingly poorly, reflecting that savings occur disproportionately during evening and winter 
hours when electricity tends to be less valuable.
...
Electric utilities in the United States, for example, spent $36 billion on energy-efficiency programs between 2006 and 2015, leading to more than 1.5 million gigawatt hours in reported total electricity savings. In addition, the U.S. Federal government has spent $12 billion since 2009 on income tax credits for residential energy-efficiency investments
...
Nine new standards promulgated by the DOE in 2016 achieve a total present value of $76 billion in energy cost savings, vs. $28 billion in avoided CO2 emissions and $5 billion in avoided NOx emissions.7 That is, more than two-thirds of the benefits come from private energy cost savings. Moreover, the hourly variation in external costs is small relative to the hourly variation in electricity prices and capacity values. Private value varies across hours by a factor of ten or more, while emission rates vary only by about a factor of two between fossil-fuel plants. 
...
Our empirical application is an energy-efficiency rebate program offered by Southern California Edison (SCE), a major investor-owned utility.... known as the Quality Installation Program. It provides incentives of up to $1,100 to households that install an energy-efficient central air conditioner.... Air conditioning is responsible for 10% of average residential electricity use and 15% of average commercial electricity use in California... Air conditioning is projected to be one of the fastest growing uses of electricity worldwide ....


The state utility commission compensates SCE for running the program by allowing the utility to pass on costs to ratepayers in the form of higher electricity prices. The Quality Installation Program includes an additional focus on proper installation of the new subsidized central air conditioner, which can further improve energy performance. 

...
The event study figure for summer shows a sharp decrease in electricity consumption in the year in which the new air conditioner is installed. The magnitude of the decrease is about 0.2 kilowatt hours per hour... As expected, winter consumption is essentially unchanged after the new air conditioner is installed.
...
On mild days, between 50 and 70 degrees Fahrenheit, estimated energy savings are zero or not statistically distinguishable from it.... From 70 to 100+ degrees, there is a steep, continuous relationship between temperature and energy savings, as expected from a new air conditioner. Air conditioner usage is largest on the hottest days, so energy-efficiency gains have the largest effect on these days. There is also a small decrease in consumption on days below 50 degrees following air conditioner replacement. This may be explained by improvements to ductwork, insulation, thermostats, or other HVAC-related upgrades that could in some cases occur as part of a central air conditioner replacement
...
During July and August there are large energy savings, particularly between noon and 10 p.m. Savings reach their nadir in the summer at 6 a.m. which is typically the coolest time of the day. During non-summer months savings are much smaller, less than 0:05 kilowatt hours saved on average per hour, compared to 0:2 to 0:3 kilowatt hours saved on average per hour during July and August.... The implied annual savings per household are 375 and 358 kilowatt hours per year, respectively.... Prior to installing a new air conditioner, program participants consumed an average of 9,820 kilowatt hours annually, so this is a 4.5% decrease in household consumption. A typical central air conditioner (3 ton, 13 SEER) in this region uses about 4,237 kilowatt hours per year, so the savings represent a 10% decrease in annual electricity consumption for air conditioning. This is broadly similar to, but slightly less than, what would be expected based on a simple engineering prediction. For example, a Department of Energy calculator shows that ignoring rebound and other factors a typical central air conditioner upgrade in Los Angeles saves 565 kilowatt hours per year.... Using hourly microdata, household by month-of-year by hour-of-day fixed effects, hour-of-sample by climate zone fixed effects, and the sample exclusions the estimate of annual program savings is 442 kilowatt hours per year.  16
...
Capacity payments are made to electricity generators to remain open and available, thereby ensuring desired reserve margins. Capacity costs are zero or close to it during off-peak hours because electricity demand can be easily met by existing inframarginal generators (plants that are not close to the margin between staying in the market and exiting). However, during peak hours large capacity payments are required to ensure desired reserve margins. 

Incorporating capacity values substantially increases the value of electricity during peak periods. In California during August, for example, capacity values increase the value of electricity during peak evening hours to between $200 and $600 per megawatt hour. And, overall, the pattern is very similar across the four approaches for allocating capacity value across hours....

Tuesday, February 28, 2017

Consequences of the Clean Water Act and the Demand for Water Quality

Abstract:
Since the 1972 U.S. Clean Water Act, government and industry have invested over $1 trillion to abate water pollution, or $100 per person-year. Over half of U.S. stream and river miles, however, still violate pollution standards. We use the most comprehensive set of files ever compiled on water pollution and its determinants, including 50 million pollution readings from 170,000 monitoring sites, to study water pollution's trends, causes, and welfare consequences. We have three main findings. First, water pollution concentrations have fallen substantially since 1972, though were declining at faster rates before then. Second, the Clean Water Act's grants to municipal wastewater treatment plants caused some of these declines. Third, the grants' estimated effects on housing values are generally smaller than the grants' costs....
The share of waters that are not fishable fell on average by about half a percentage point per year, and the share that are not swimmable fell at the same rate. In total over the period 1972-2001, the share of waters that are not fishable and the share not swimmable each fell by 11 percentage points. Each of the four pollutants which are part of these fishable and swimmable definitions declined rapidly during this period. Fecal coliforms had the fastest rate of decrease, at 2.8 percent per year. BOD, dissolved oxygen deficits, and total suspended solids all declined more slowly, at about 1.5 percent per year.

Trends in all these pollutants since the Clean Water Act are large, but trends before the Clean Water Act were larger. For example, BOD was falling by 3 percent per year before the Clean Water Act and 1.5 percent after it. We find pre/post 1972 trend breaks of comparable magnitudes for all the other pollutants. We interpret these pre-1972 trends somewhat cautiously since, as discussed earlier, relatively few monitoring sites recorded data before the 1970s, and fewer long-term monitoring sites operated in the 1960s.
...
We find that [Clean Water Act] grants cause large and statistically significant decreases in pollution. Each grant decreases dissolved oxygen deficits by 0.8 percentage points, and decreases the probability that downstream waters are not fishable by 0.7 percentage points. The other pollutants decrease as well | BOD falls by about 3.4 percent, fecal coliforms fall by 8.5 percent, and the probability that downstream waters are not swimmable by about half a percentage point. The point estimate implies that each grant decreases TSS by one percent, though is imprecise. TSS comes primarily from non-point sources like agriculture and urban runoff, so is less closely related to municipal wastewater.

Event study graphs support these results. These graphs are estimated from specifications corresponding to equation.  In years before a grant, the coefficients are all statistically indistinguishable from zero, have modest magnitude, and have no clear trend.... This implies that pollution levels in upstream and downstream waters had similar trends before grants were received. In the years after a grant, downstream waters have 1-2 percent lower dissolved oxygen deficits, and become 1-2 percent less likely to violate fishing standards. These effects grow in magnitude over the first ten years, are statistically significant in this period, and remain negative for about 30 years after a grant.
...
The cost to increase dissolved oxygen saturation in a river-mile by 10 percentage points.... .The simplest specification ... implies that it cost $0.57 million per year to increase dissolved oxygen saturation in a river-mile by ten percent; the broadest specification ... implies that it cost $0.54 million per year. The annual cost to make a river-mile fishable ranges from $1.8 million in the simplest specification ... to $1.5 million in the richest specification....  The grants program made 16,000 river-miles fishable.
...
The estimates ... are generally consistent with near complete pass-through, i.e., little or no crowding out or in beyond the required municipal capital copayment. The Panel A pass-through estimates range from 1.15 to 1.27 in real terms or 1.53 in nominal, which mean that city expenditure increased by around the amount of the typical copay (which was typically a third of the federal grant). Panel B ... includes the local copayment in the main explanatory variable,... and the estimates imply pass-through rates of 0.86 to 0.94 in real terms or 1.09 in nominal terms.  
,,,
Table 5 analyzes how Clean Water Act grants affect housing. Column (1) shows estimates for homes within a quarter mile of downstream waters. Column (2) adds controls for dwelling characteristics, and for baseline covariates interacted with year fixed effects. Column (3) include all homes within 1 mile, and column (4) includes homes within 25 miles.
Panel A reports estimates of how grants affect log mean home values. The positive coefficients in the richer specifications of columns (2) through (4) are consistent with increases in home values, though most are statistically insignificant. Column (4) implies that each grant increases mean home values within 25 miles of affected waters by three hundredths of a percentage point. The 0.25 or 1.0 mile estimates are slightly larger than the 25 mile estimate, which is consistent with the idea that residents nearer to the river benefit more from water quality. Panel B analyzes how grants affect log mean rental values. These estimates are generally smaller than the estimates for housing. The estimate in column (4), including homes within a 25 mile radius of downstream rivers, is small but actually negative.

Panels A and B reflect the classic hedonic model, with fixed housing stock. Panels C and D estimate the effect of grants on log housing units (panel C) or the log of the total value of the housing stock (panel D). In the presence of elastic housing, measuring only price effects (as in Panels A and B) could understate willingness-to-pay for local amenities. Moreover, many cities have had substantial waterfront development, which could be related to water quality.

Panels C and D suggest similar conclusions as Panels A and B. Most of these estimates are small and actually negative. One is marginally significant (Panel C, column 1), though the precision and point estimate diminish with the controls of column (2). Column (4) in of Panel D literally implies that each grant decreases the total value of the housing stock within a 25 mile radius of downstream waters by one point five hundredths of a percentage point.


Figure 4 shows event study graphs, which suggest similar conclusions as these regressions. Panel A shows modest evidence that in the years after a plant receives a grant, the values of homes within 0.25 miles of the downstream river increase. The increases are statistically insignificant in most years and small in magnitude. Panel B shows no evidence that homes within 25 miles of the downstream river increase after a treatment plant receives a grant.
We also report a range of sensitivity analyses, which are broadly in line with the main results.
...
Considering all owner-occupied homes within 25 miles of the river, the estimated ratio of the grants aggregate effects on home values to the grants’ costs is 0.25. Adding rental units in column (3) does not change this estimate out to two decimal points.
...
Under [the] ... three approaches, the ratios of measured benefits to costs are -0.11 (0.16), 0.11 (0.31), and 0.11 (0.10), respectively.
...
Row 8 finds that grants to declining urban areas have slightly lower ratios, while the ratio for high amenity areas is greater. Finally, row 9 tests for differences in the housing market response by census region. This specification finds that grants to the Northeast have smaller ratios, while grants to the south have larger ratios around 0.73. None of these ratios in rows 6-9 are significantly different than that of the mean grant.

The map in Appendix Figure 10 shows heterogeneity in the ratio of measured benefits to costs across U.S. counties. This map assumes the same hedonic price function nationally and reflects spatial heterogeneity in the density of housing units. Specifically, these estimates divide treatment plants into ten deciles of the number of people in 2000 living within 25 miles of downstream river segments. They then use the regression estimates from column 4 of Table 5 to calculate the ratio of the change in the value of housing and grant costs, separately for each decile.
39 Finally, we average this ratio across all plants in each county.

The map shows that the ratio of measured benefits to costs is much larger in more populated counties. The bottom decile of counties, for example, includes ratios of measured benefits to costs of below 0.01. The top decile of counties includes ratios between 0.31 and 0.45. Grants and population are both highly skewed|37 percent of grant costs and 54 percent of population are in the top decile.

We take three overall conclusions from this analysis of heterogeneity. First, we find suggestive evidence that ratios of measured benefits to costs follow sensible patterns, though not all estimates are precise Second, none of these subsets of grants considered has a ratio of measured benefits to costs above one, though many of the confidence regions cannot reject a ratio of one. The largest ratios of estimated benefits to costs are for areas where outdoor fishing or swimming is common (ratio of 0.57), for high amenity urban areas (ratio of 0.63), and in the South (ratio of 0.74).
 

Report: Hawaii, ConnecticutT, MA, RI, and AK Households Save Most on Overall Utility Bills due to Appliance Standards

The average American family saved nearly $500 on utility bills in 2015 as a direct result of existing efficiency standards for appliances and lighting, according to a new report issued today by the Appliance Standards Awareness Project (ASAP) and the American Council for an Energy-Efficient Economy (ACEEE). The report details average household savings for all 50 states and the nation’s capital in four categories:  household utility bill savings; electricity savings; natural gas and oil savings; and water savings. The top 10 states for each are ranked. Consumers in Hawaii save the most on overall household utility bills — ,,, $945.

Appliance standards protect consumers and save them money by eliminating energy- and water-wasting products in the market, while preserving the performance and features consumers value and encouraging manufacturers to develop and bring to market products with improved efficiency performance.
Available online at http://www.appliance-standards.org/documents/reports/white-paper-overview, the new ASAP/ACEEE report updates previous estimates of the consumer and business benefits achieved by all existing national standards. In addition to the consumer savings, ASAP/ACEEE show big benefits for businesses too. Total business utility bill savings from standards reached nearly $23 billion in 2015. Business energy bill savings equaled 8% of total business spending on electricity and natural gas.

Average household savings by state ranged from 11-27% of total consumer utility bills, with a national average savings of 16%. The top 10 states for household utility bill savings from existing appliance standards are: 

Consumers in states with highest bill savings save the most, because they tend to pay the most for energy. Other factors affecting savings include the types of appliances consumers have (e.g. electric versus gas water heaters), and how much cooling and heating they use and household size. States appearing at the bottom of the overall utility bill savings list include: Washington (50), North Dakota (49), Idaho (48), Montana (47), West Virginia (46), Wyoming (45), Oregon (44), Nebraska (43), Arkansas (42) and Louisiana (41). Savings in 2015 for the bottom ten states were still significant, ranging from $360-$405.
...
The top 10 states for per household electricity savings span the Southeast plus Texas and Arizona. These tend to be the states with the greatest air conditioner use and where electric water heating is most common.  The top 10 states are as follows:

The top 10 states for per-household gas and heating oil savings are those with the largest heating needs (which is where gas and oil heating is most common) and where gas water heating is prevalent. They are as follows: